• Skip to primary navigation
  • Skip to main content
  • Skip to primary sidebar
Harvard Law School Bankruptcy Roundtable

Harvard Law School Bankruptcy Roundtable

  • Blog
  • About Us
  • Coverage-in-Depth
    • Crypto-Bankruptcy
    • Purdue Pharma Bankruptcy
    • Texas Two-Step and the Future of Mass Tort Bankruptcy
  • Subscribe
  • Show Search
Hide Search

The Backstop Party

By Professor Vince Buccola (University of Chicago Law School), Adi Marcovich Gross (Columbia Law School and The Wharton School), and Professor Matthew McBrady (University of Virginia Darden School of Business)

Vince Buccola, Adi Marcovich Gross, and Matthew McBrady

Bankruptcy exit financing has become a site of recurring conflict in the intra-class creditor skirmishes that now so often mark corporate reorganization. When creditors in an ad hoc group sufficiently large to accept a plan of reorganization on behalf of an impaired class agree to underwrite, or “backstop,” the debtor’s plan-contemplated capital raise, creditors who hold identical claims but are excluded from the backstop group cry foul that the Bankruptcy Code bars their unequal treatment. All-or-nothing arguments have proved unsatisfying, however, because, on the best reading of the Code, the merits depend on a matter of fact that is not readily ascertainable: is the debtor offering backstop parties a competitive risk-adjusted return for the risk they will bear, or something more?

This article reports the results of a study of the returns to equity rights offering backstop commitments in 49 bankruptcies since 2016. We find evidence that backstop parties face little risk and garner strong positive returns on their capital commitments. For example, the value of the securities sold in an offering exceeded the exercise price in 18 of the 19 deals for which an arm’s-length estimate of value is available—on average by a factor of 2. We estimate that, on average, backstop creditors realized 16 cents per dollar of eligible claim more than did similarly situated creditors who participated optimally in the offering but were not part of the ad hoc group. Although the small sample size warrants caution in interpretation, our results indicate that backstop parties in the typical case are compensated for more than their willingness to risk capital.

Click here to read the full article.

Written by:
Editor
Published on:
June 17, 2025

Categories: Bankruptcy, Chapter 11, Cramdown and Priority, Empirical, plan confirmationTags: Backstop, Bankruptcy, Chapter 11, plan confirmation, Priority, rights offering, syndicated

Primary Sidebar

Categories

Recent Posts

  • Bankruptcy Law’s Doctrinal Evolution: An Empirical Study July 1, 2025
  • Judge Goldblatt Reconsiders What Constitutes“Consent” Post Purdue Pharma June 24, 2025
  • The Backstop Party June 17, 2025

View by Subject Matter

363 sales Anthony Casey Bankruptcy Bankruptcy administration Bankruptcy Courts Bankruptcy Reform Chapter 11 Chapter 15 Claims Trading Cleary Gottlieb Comparative Law Corporate Governance COVID-19 cramdown David Skeel Derivatives DIP Financing Empirical FIBA Financial Crisis fraudulent transfer Jared A. Ellias Jevic Johnson & Johnson Jones Day Mark G. Douglas Mark Roe plan confirmation Priority Purdue Pharma Purdue Pharma bankruptcy restructuring Safe Harbors Schulte Roth & Zabel Sovereign Debt SPOE Stephen Lubben Structured Dismissals Supreme Court syndicated Texas Two-Step Trust Indenture Act Valuation Weil Gotshal Workouts

Footer

Harvard Law School Bankruptcy Roundtable

1563 Massachusetts Ave,
Cambridge, MA 02138
Accessibility | Digital Accessibility | Harvard Law School

Copyright © 2023 The President and Fellows of Harvard College

Copyright © 2025 · Navigation Pro on Genesis Framework · WordPress · Log in